Aristotle therefore, himself, tells us, what barred the way to his further analysis; it was the absence of any concept of value. What is that equal something, that common substance, which admits of the value of the beds being expressed by a house? Such a thing, in truth, cannot exist, says Aristotle. And why not? Compared with the beds, the house does represent something equal to them, in so far as it represents what is really equal, both in the beds and the house. And that is human labour.
There was, however, an important fact which prevented Aristotle from seeing that, to attribute value to commodities, is merely a mode of expressing all labour as equal human labour, and consequently as labour of equal quality. Greek society was founded upon slavery, and had, therefore, for its natural basis, the inequality of men and of their labour-powers. The secret of the expression of value, namely, that all kinds of labour are equal and equivalent, because, and so far as they are human labour in general, cannot be deciphered, until the notion of human equality has already acquired the fixity of a popular prejudice. This, however, is possible only in a society in which the great mass of the produce of labour takes the form of commodities, in which, consequently, the dominant relation between man and man, is that of owners of commodities. The brilliancy of Aristotle's genius is shown by this alone, that he discovered, in the expression of the value of commodities, a relation of equality. The peculiar conditions of the society in which he lived, alone prevented him from discovering what, "in truth," was at the bottom of this equality.
Our analysis has shown, that the form or expression of the value of a commodity originates in the nature of value, and not that value and its magnitude originate in the mode of their expression as exchange-value. This, however, is the delusion as well of the mercantilists and their recent revivers, Ferrier, Ganilh,(23) and others, as also of their antipodes, the modern bagmen of Free-trade, such as Bastiat. The mercantilists lay special stress on the qualitative aspect of the expression of value, and consequently on the equivalent form of commodities, which attains its full perfection in money. The modern hawkers of Free-trade, who must get rid of their article at any price, on the other hand, lay most stress on the quantitative aspect of the relative form of value. For them there consequently exists neither value, nor magnitude of value, anywhere except in its expression by means of the exchange relation of commodities, that is, in the daily list of prices current. Macleod, who has taken upon himself to dress up the confused ideas of Lombard Street in the most learned finery, is a successful cross between the superstitious mercantilists, and the enlightened Free-trade bagmen.
A close scrutiny of the expression of the value of A in terms of B, contained in the equation expressing the value-relation of A to B, has shown us that, within that relation, the bodily form of A figures only as a use-value, the bodily form of B only as the form or aspect of value. The opposition or contrast existing internally in each commodity between use-value and value, is, therefore, made evident externally by two commodities being placed in such relation to each other, that the commodity whose value it is sought to express, figures directly as a mere use-value, while the commodity in which that value is to be expressed, figures directly as mere exchange-value. Hence the elementary form of value of a commodity is the elementary form in which the contrast contained in that commodity, between use-value and value, becomes apparent.
Every product of labour is, in all states of society, a use-value; but it is only at a definite historical epoch in a society's development that such a product becomes a commodity, viz., at the epoch when the labour spent on the production of a useful article becomes expressed as one of the objective qualities of that article, i.e., as its value. It therefore follows that the elementary value-form is also the primitive form under which a product of labour appears historically as a commodity, and that the gradual transformation of such products into commodities, proceeds pari passu with the development of the value-form.
We perceive, at first sight, the deficiencies of the elementary form of value: it is a mere germ, which must undergo a series of metamorphoses before it can ripen into the price-form.
The expression of the value of commodity A in terms of any other commodity B, merely distinguishes the value from the use-value of A, and therefore places A merely in a relation of exchange with a single different commodity, B; but it is still far from expressing A's qualitative equality, and quantitative proportionality, to all commodities. To the elementary relative value-form of a commodity, there corresponds the single equivalent form of one other commodity. Thus, in the relative expression of value of the linen, the coat assumes the form of equivalent, or of being directly exchangeable, only in relation to a single commodity, the linen.
Nevertheless, the elementary form of value passes by an easy transition into a more complete form. It is true that by means of the elementary form, the value of a commodity A, becomes expressed in terms of one, and only one, other commodity. But that one may be a commodity of any kind, coat, iron, corn, or anything else. Therefore, according as A is placed in relation with one or the other, we get for one and the same commodity, different elementary expressions of value.(24) The number of such possible expressions is limited only by the number of the different kinds of commodities distinct from it. The isolated expression of A's value, is therefore convertible into a series, prolonged to any length, of the different elementary expressions of that value.
1. The Expanded Relative form of value
In the first form, 20 yds. of linen=1 coat, it might, for ought that otherwise appears, be pure accident, that these two commodities are exchangeable in definite quantities. In the second form, on the contrary, we perceive at once the background that determines, and is essentially different from, this accidental appearance. The value of the linen remains unaltered in magnitude, whether expressed in coats, coffee, or iron, or in numberless different commodities, the property of as many different owners. The accidental relation between two individual commodity-owners disappears. It becomes plain, that it is not the exchange of commodities which regulates the magnitude of their value; but, on the contrary, that it is the magnitude of their value which controls their exchange proportions.
The expanded relative value-form is, however, nothing but the sum of the
elementary relative expressions or equations of the first kind, such as
20 yards of linen= 1 coat
The forms A and B were fit only to express the value of a commodity as
something distinct from its use-value or material form.
The first- form, A, furnishes such equations as the following:- 1
coat=20 yards of linen, 10 lbs. of tea=1/2 a ton of iron. The value of
the coat is equated to linen, that of the tea to iron. But to be equated
to linen, and again to iron, is to be as different as are linen and
iron. This forms it is plain, occurs practically only in the first
beginning, when the products of labour are converted into commodities by
accidental and occasional exchanges.
The second form, B, distinguishes, in a more adequate manner than the
first, the value of a commodity from its use-value, for the value of the
coat is there placed in contrast under all possible shapes with the
bodily form of the coat; it is equated to linen, to iron, to tea, in
short, to everything else, only not to itself, the coat. On the other
hand, any general expression of value common to all is directly
excluded; for, in the equation of value of each commodity, all other
commodities now appear only under the form of equivalents. The expanded
form of value comes into actual existence for the first time so soon as
a particular product of labour, such as cattle, is no longer
exceptionally, but habitually, exchanged for various other commodities.
The third and lastly developed form expresses the values of the whole
world of commodities in terms of a single commodity set apart for the
purpose, namely, the linen, and thus represents to us their values by
means of their equality with linen. The value of every commodity is now,
by being equated to linen, not only differentiated from its own use-
value, but from all other use-values generally, and is, by that very
fact, expressed as that which is common to all commodities. By this
form, commodities are, for the first time, effectively brought into
relation with one another as values, or made to appear as exchange-
values.
The two earlier forms either express the value of each commodity in
terms of a single commodity of a different kind, or in a series of many
such commodities. In both cases, it is, so to say, the special business
of each single commodity to find an expression for its value, and this
it does without the help of the others. These others, with respect to
the former, play the passive parts of equivalents. The general form of
value, C, results from the joint action of the whole world of
commodities, and from that alone. A commodity can acquire a general
expression of its value only by all other commodities, simultaneously
with it, expressing their values in the same equivalent; and every new
commodity must follow suit. It thus becomes evident that since the
existence of commodities as values is purely social, this social
existence can be expressed by the totality of their social relations
alone, and consequently that the form of their value must be a socially
recognised form.
All commodities being equated to linen now appear not only as
qualitatively equal as values generally, but also as values whose
magnitudes are capable of comparison. By expressing the magnitudes of
their values in one and the same material, the linen, those magnitudes
are also compared with each other For instance, 10 Ibs. of tea=20 yards
of linen, and 40 lbs. of coffee=20 yards of linen. Therefore, 10 Ibs of
tea=40 Ibs. of coffee. In other words, there is contained in 1 lb. of
coffee only one-fourth as much substance of value (labour) as is contained
in 1 lb. of tea
The general form of relative value, embracing the whole world of
commodities, converts the single commodity that is excluded from the
rest, and made to play the part of equivalent -here the linen- into the
universal equivalent. The bodily form of the linen is now the form
assumed in common by the values of all commodities; it therefore becomes
directly exchangeable with all and every of them. The substance linen
becomes the visible incarnation, the social chrysalis state of every
kind of human labour. Weaving, which is the labour of certain private
individuals producing a particular article, linen, acquires in
consequence a social character, the character of equality with all other
kinds of labour. The innumerable equations of which the general form of
value is composed, equate in turn the labour embodied in the linen to
that embodied in every other commodity, and they thus convert weaving
into the general form of manifestation of undifferentiated human labour.
In this manner the labour realised in the values of commodities is
presented not only under its negative aspect, under which abstraction is
made from every concrete form and useful property of actual work, but
its own positive nature is made to reveal itself expressly. The general
value-form is the reduction of all kinds of actual labour to their
common character of being human labour generally, of being the
expenditure of human labour-power.
The general value-form, which represents all products of labour as mere
congelations of undifferentiated human labour, shows by its very
structure that it is the social resume of the world of commodities. That
form consequently makes it indisputably evident that in the world of
commodities the character possessed by all labour of being human labour
constitutes its specific social character.
The primary or isolated relative form of value of one commodity converts
some other commodity into an isolated equivalent. The expanded form of
relative value, which is the expression of the value of one commodity in
terms of all other commodities, endows those other commodities with the
character of particular equivalents differing in kind. And lastly, a
particular kind of commodity acquires the character of universal
equivalent, because all other commodities make it the material in which
they uniformly express their value.
The antagonism between the relative form of value and the equivalent
form, the two poles of the value-form, is developed concurrently with
that form itself.
The first form, 20 yds. of linen=one coat, already contains this
antagonism, without as yet fixing it. According as we read this equation
forwards or backwards, the parts played by the linen and the coat are
different. In the one case the relative value of the linen is expressed
in the coat, in the other case the relative value of the coat is
expressed in the linen. In this first form of value, therefore, it is
difficult to grasp the polar contrast.
Form B shows that only one single commodity at a time can completely
expand its relative value, and that it acquires this expanded form only
because, and in so far as, all other commodities are, with respect to
it, equivalents. Here we cannot reverse the equation, as we can the
equation 20 yds. of linen=1 coat, without altering its general
character, and converting it from the expanded form of value into the
general form of value.
Finally, the form C gives to the world of commodities a general social
relative form of value, because, and in so far as, thereby all
commodities, with the exception of one, are excluded from the equivalent
form. A single commodity, the linen, appears therefore to have acquired
the character of direct exchangeability with every other commodity
because, and in so far as, this character is denied to every other
commodity.(26)
The commodity that figures as universal equivalent, is, on the other
hand, excluded from the relative value-form. If the linen, or any other
commodity serving as universal equivalent, were, at the same time, to
share in the relative form of value, it would have to serve as its own
equivalent. We should then have 20 yds. of linen=20 yds. of linen; this
tautology expresses neither value, nor magnitude of value. In order to
express the relative value of the universal equivalent, we must rather
reverse the form C. This equivalent has no relative form of value in
common with other commodities, but its value is relatively expressed by
a never ending series of other commodities.
Thus, the expanded form of relative value, or form B, now shows itself
as the specific form of relative value for the equivalent commodity.
The particular commodity, with whose bodily form the equivalent form is
thus socially identified, now becomes the money-commodity, or serves as
money. It becomes the special social function of that commodity, and
consequently its social monopoly, to play within the world of
commodities the part of the universal equivalent. Amongst the
commodities which, in form B, figure as particular equivalents of the
linen, and, in form C, express in common their relative values in linen,
this foremost place has been attained by one in particular- namely,
gold. If, then, in form C we replace the linen by gold, we get,
Gold is now money with reference to all other commodities only because
it was previously, with reference to them, a simple commodity. Like all
other commodities, it was also capable of serving as an equivalent,
either as simple equivalent in isolated exchanges, or as particular
equivalent by the side of others. Gradually it began to serve, within
varying limits, as universal equivalent. So soon as it monopolises this
position in the expression of value for the world of commodities, it
becomes the money commodity, and then, and not till then, does form D
become distinct from form C, and the general form of value become
changed into the money-form.
The elementary expression of the relative value of a single commodity,
such as linen, in terms of the commodity, such as gold, that plays the
part of money, is the price-form of that commodity. The price-form of
the linen is therefore
20 yards of linen=2 ounces of gold, or, if 2 ounces of gold when coined
are 2, 20 yards of linen= 2.
The difficulty in forming a concept of the money-form, consists in
clearly comprehending the universal equivalent form, and as a necessary
corollary, the general form of value, form C. The latter is deducible
from form B, the expanded form of value, the essential component element
of which, we saw, is form A, 20 yards of linen= 1 coat or x commodity
A=y commodity B. The simple commodity-form is therefore the germ of the
money-form.
20 yards of linen= 10 Ibs. of tea, etc.
Each of these implies the corresponding inverted equation,
1 coat=20 yards of linen
10 Ibs. of tea=20 yards of linen, etc.
In fact, when a person exchanges his linen for many other commodities,
and thus expresses its value in a series of other commodities, it
necessarily follows, that the various owners of the latter exchange them
for the linen, and consequently express the value of their various
commodities in one and the same third commodity, the linen. If then, we
reverse the series, 20 yards of linen=l coat or=10 Ibs. of tea, etc.,
that is to say, if we give expression to the converse relation already
implied in the series, we get,
40 Ibs. of coffee |
1 quarter of corn >= 20 yards of linen
2 ounces of gold
1/2 a ton of iron |
x com A., etc. |
1 coat =|
10 lbs. of tea =|
40 lbs. of coffee => 2 ounces of gold
1 qr. of corn =|
1/2 a ton of iron =|
x commodity A =/
In passing from form A to form B, and from the latter to form C, the
changes are fundamental. On the other hand, there is no difference
between forms C and D, except that, in the latter, gold has assumed the
equivalent form in the place of linen. Gold is in form D, what linen was
in form C-the universal equivalent. The progress consists in this alone,
that the character of direct and universal exchangeability- in other
words, that the universal equivalent form--has now, by social custom,
become finally identified with the substance, gold.
Return to Hanover College
Return to History Department
historians@hanover.edu